Difference between revisions of "Dynamic Input-Output Models"

From Open Risk Manual
(Formula)
 
(11 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
 
== Definition ==
 
== Definition ==
'''Dynamic Input-Output Models''' is a category of various possible generalization of the basic [[Input-Output Model]] that allow accounting for more sophisticated temporal behavior<ref>Eurostat Manual of Supply, Use and Input-Output Tables, 2008 edition</ref>
+
'''Dynamic Input-Output Models''' is a category of various possible generalization of the basic [[Input-Output Model]] that allow accounting for more sophisticated temporal behavior <ref>Eurostat Manual of Supply, Use and Input-Output Tables, 2008 edition</ref>, <ref>R.E. Miller and P.D. Blair, Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions, Second Edition, Cambridge University Press, 2009</ref>
 +
 
 +
Dynamic (inter-temporal) frameworks can address phenomena such as stock accumulation (both physical and capital), technology changes and other time-dependent developments that cannot be represented in a stationary equilibrium model.
 +
 
 +
Mathematically the equations of the standard IO model become finite difference equations relating two or more timepoints.
  
 
== Formula  ==
 
== Formula  ==
The typical equations of the dynamic input-output model:
+
Typical equations of a dynamic input-output model are:
* X = AX + C + Dt
+
* <math>X_t = A X_t + C_t + D_t</math>
* D = BX - BXt t+1 t
+
* <math>D_t = B (X_{t+1} - X_{t})</math>
* Xt = AXt + Ct + BXt + 1 - BXt
+
* <math>X_t = A X_t + C_t + B (X_{t+1} - X_{t})</math>
* (I A + B) Xt = Ct + BX
+
* <math>(I - A + B) X_t = C_t + B X_{t+1}</math>
  
  
The production of period t is defined:
+
The total production vector X of period t is related to the production in period t+1 through equation:
* X = (I – A + B)-1 (C + BX )
 
  
 +
:<math>
 +
X_t = (I - A + B)^{-1} (C_t + B X_{t+1} )
 +
</math>
  
while the production of period t+1 is determined by:
+
while the production of period t+1 is related to the production in period t through the inverse equation:
* X =B-1[(I – A + B)X - C ]
 
  
 +
:<math>
 +
X_{t+1} = B^{-1}[(I - A + B) X_t - C_t]
 +
</math>
  
 
Where:
 
Where:
* Y = final demand
+
* Y is the [[Final Demand]] which splits into C + D, where in turn
* I = unit matrix
+
** C is the exogenous final demand (consumption)
* A = input coefficients for intermediates
+
** D is the induced investment
* (I-A)-1 = matrix of cumulative input coefficients (inverse)
+
* B are the input coefficients for capital (the amount of sector i product (in dollars) held as capital stock for production of one dollar’s worth of output by sector j).
* B = input coefficients for capital
+
* I is the unit (identity) matrix
* C = exogenous final demand (consumption)
+
* A are input coefficients for intermediate production ([[Technical Coefficient Matrix]])
* D = induced investment
+
* <math>(I - A)^{-1}</math>  is the matrix of cumulative input coefficients ([[Leontief Inverse Matrix]])
* T = time index
+
* t is the time index of successive periods
 +
 
  
 +
This is a system of linear difference equations, since the values of the variables X are related to different periods of time. NB: In this example the coefficient matrices are assumed time invariant.
  
This is a system of linear difference equations, since the values of the variables are related to different periods of time. Consumption is expected to grow at the annual rate (1+m)t.
+
If B is zero (no amounts held in capital stock), the equations reduce to the standard (stationary) model.
  
 
== Issues and Challenges ==
 
== Issues and Challenges ==
Practical problems relate to the matrix B of capital coefficients.
+
* Practical problems relate to the matrix B of capital coefficients. Only a few sectors produce capital goods. Therefore it can not be expected that matrix B has an inverse. There is a large literature on the singularity problem in the dynamic input-output model and many problems remain for empirical applications.
 +
 
 +
== Further Resources ==
 +
* [https://www.openriskacademy.com/course/view.php?id=70 Crash Course on Input-Output Model Mathematics]
 +
* [https://www.openriskacademy.com/course/view.php?id=64 Introduction to Input-Output Models using Python]
  
 
== References ==
 
== References ==

Latest revision as of 16:39, 16 November 2023

Definition

Dynamic Input-Output Models is a category of various possible generalization of the basic Input-Output Model that allow accounting for more sophisticated temporal behavior [1], [2]

Dynamic (inter-temporal) frameworks can address phenomena such as stock accumulation (both physical and capital), technology changes and other time-dependent developments that cannot be represented in a stationary equilibrium model.

Mathematically the equations of the standard IO model become finite difference equations relating two or more timepoints.

Formula

Typical equations of a dynamic input-output model are:

  • X_t = A X_t + C_t + D_t
  • D_t = B (X_{t+1} - X_{t})
  • X_t = A X_t + C_t + B (X_{t+1} - X_{t})
  • (I - A + B) X_t = C_t + B X_{t+1}


The total production vector X of period t is related to the production in period t+1 through equation:


X_t = (I - A + B)^{-1} (C_t + B X_{t+1} )

while the production of period t+1 is related to the production in period t through the inverse equation:


X_{t+1} = B^{-1}[(I - A + B) X_t - C_t]

Where:

  • Y is the Final Demand which splits into C + D, where in turn
    • C is the exogenous final demand (consumption)
    • D is the induced investment
  • B are the input coefficients for capital (the amount of sector i product (in dollars) held as capital stock for production of one dollar’s worth of output by sector j).
  • I is the unit (identity) matrix
  • A are input coefficients for intermediate production (Technical Coefficient Matrix)
  • (I - A)^{-1} is the matrix of cumulative input coefficients (Leontief Inverse Matrix)
  • t is the time index of successive periods


This is a system of linear difference equations, since the values of the variables X are related to different periods of time. NB: In this example the coefficient matrices are assumed time invariant.

If B is zero (no amounts held in capital stock), the equations reduce to the standard (stationary) model.

Issues and Challenges

  • Practical problems relate to the matrix B of capital coefficients. Only a few sectors produce capital goods. Therefore it can not be expected that matrix B has an inverse. There is a large literature on the singularity problem in the dynamic input-output model and many problems remain for empirical applications.

Further Resources

References

  1. Eurostat Manual of Supply, Use and Input-Output Tables, 2008 edition
  2. R.E. Miller and P.D. Blair, Input-Output Analysis: Foundations and Extensions, Second Edition, Cambridge University Press, 2009